Pagina-afbeeldingen
PDF
ePub

would rather start out at once into some indifferent job of any kind than train for real work. These are admittedly difficult folk to deal with, for in most cases they will become 'repeaters,' that is, men who will be always back on the odd job of the Employment Exchanges. The army education scheme is particularly useful here, for it will drill some sense into this officer before he is able to leave the army, and the unqualified man with no prospects will not be the first officer to be released.

life applies to the able-bodied as well as to the disabled officer is all to the advantage of the latter. A scheme for the employment of the disabled alone must always suffer under the disadvantages associated with the word charity, the appeal must tend to be directed to the sentiments as well as to the business instincts of the prospective employer. As now arranged, a demand will be created for the brain power available in the ex-officer irrespective of his physical condition. The ex-officer will be in demand, not because of his past. services, but because of the efficiency he has attained through a course of training which is the last word in modern methods. The disabled officer will find his job, not on the score of his disability, but in spite of it, because the whole class of ex-officers will have proved their superiority as a reservoir That the scheme of resettlement in civil of the nation's brain power.

This, by itself, is not enough, nor will anything be enough until the parents of young officers, the wives of young officers, and the employers and everybody interested in any individual officer, all insist that the officer or exofficer should qualify according to his capacities, but qualify for some sort of permanent job.

[blocks in formation]

All stir, I know beneath the sparkling beech

Your dreams run on 'I swear that voice was hers!'
(My footfall stays) -'O! welcomed, late my bride!'

ECONOMICS, TRADE, AND FINANCE

WAR'S FINANCIAL PARADOX

BY HARTLEY WITHERS A CORRESPONDENT desires elucidation of the following puzzle:

[ocr errors]

'It is said that the war has "cost" £8,000,000,000; in other words, that sum has been "expended" by Great Britain on the war. But looking round we see plenty of money knocking about. Wages are high and have been earned by hard work. This huge sum has been spent, but there are no signs that the country is poorer for it. There must, therefore, be plenty more where that came from.

'More than that; most workingmen have never had such a good time. Their children have been better fed and clothed. Besides plenty of wages there are separation allowances and pensions. Millions have been made, too, by masters, contractors, and profiteers. A good slice of this has been taken, very properly, by the government as excess profit tax, but the huge sums subscribed by wealthy people for war loans show that they have put by an enormous amount. This stands to their credit, and although £8,000,000,000 has been spent, there must be plenty more in hand.'

Two distinct problems seem to be involved by these questions, one of which is quite simple and the other rather difficult. Number one is the fact that in spite of the huge expenditure on the war, there is more money than ever in the pockets and the bank balances of its citizens. Number two is the fact that again, in spite of the huge expenditure on the war, a great many people, probably the majority of the population, are actually better off.

There is no difficulty about seeing why there is much more money about, because money when it is spent does not thereby vanish, except when it is spent abroad and actually shipped in gold or notes. When the government spends money at home it first has to get it, by taxes or loans, and then pays it out to contractors, or soldiers and sailors, or their dependents, or to civil servants, or members of Parliament, or anyone whom it may be rewarding for work done, or alleged to be done, for the service of the country. These workers hand over the goods and services needed and take payment and the money is still in their pockets or at their bank ready to go round the same circuit, being paid in taxes or subscribed to loans and then again paid out against fresh goods and services supplied. In ordinary times the quantity of money of all kinds, including checks drawn on banks, that is being turned over in the country cannot be increased indefinitely unless more gold comes in because there is a rough relation between the amount of gold in the Bank of England and in the other banks and the amount of credit that the banks are prepared to create; and if the banks create credit too fast, the machinery of exchange sets up a process that corrects this excess. The creation of credit-money faster than of goods depreciates the buying power of the money, in other words, raises prices; imports of goods are stimulated, exports are checked, and a balance of imports has to be paid for in gold which reduces still further the proportion between gold and credits, and checks the creation of the latter. In war time this pretty and effective sys

tem of checks and balances does not work. For a long time our gold reserves were protected by Tirpitz and his submarines, which made it too expensive a business to send gold abroad, owing to the high premiums that had to be paid against the submarine risk; moreover, there was and is still, in spite of the fighting being over, a notion that it is not patriotic at such a crisis to send gold abroad any more than it is right to demand gold from our banks to carry in our pockets. And so the relation between our stock of gold and the creation of credit no longer exists, and the restoration of this relation is one of the first things needful for getting our currency back on to a sound basis. In the meantime our war governments have been able to take advantage of a wholly abnormal state of affairs to finance a large part of the war expenditure, not by taking or getting our money through taxes and loans, but by printing paper currency and by making the banks create credits for them against government securities placed with them. Paper has been printed so rapidly that according to an estimate made by a committee lately appointed to inquire into the question of currency and foreign exchanges after the war, the amount of legal tender money in bank reserves and in circulation has risen from 180,000,000 on June 30, 1914, to 383,000,000 on July 10, 1918, since when the printing press has worked with accelerated vigor. The increase in bank credits has also been on an enormous scale; and it is very safe to expect that the total deposits entered in their books, which were 1,070,000,000 (not including those of the Bank of England) before the war, will be found to have totaled something like 2,000,000,000 on December 31 last. With an addition of over 200,000,000 to legal tender money (coin and notes)

and probably of about 1,000,000,000 to bankers' book-keeping money, it is not surprising in the first place that, in spite of the war's expenditure, 'we see plenty of money knocking about' and, in the second, that the said money, though comfortably plentiful, is lamentably deficient in the only quality for which money is valued, namely, in buying power.

Owing to this disagreeable fact the appearance of wealth that the circulation of so much money and the existence of such large bank deposits give, is largely if not wholly fictitious. The inquirer who puts the conundrum observes that this huge sum has been spent but there are no signs that the country is poorer for it.' But is that so? The wealth or poverty of a country is surely best tested by the ability of its citizens to get the goods and services that they need, or think they need; and we know that in spite of the flood of money many of the good things that we used to enjoy are often difficult and sometimes impossible to get in these times. So much labor had been diverted to war purposes that the remnant has not sufficed to provide us with many conveniences that used to be plentiful. Traveling facilities, haircutting and barbers, domestic servants, houses in certain places, some kinds of fruit, cigarettes and tobaccos, wines, spirits, and beer, are obvious examples of service givers and goods that are much less plentiful than they were. And if we look deeper into the problem and remember that we lost about 8,500,000 tons of shipping by submarine attack, and have sold, perhaps, 800,000,000 worth of securities to foreigners in exchange for munitions and food, and borrowed over 1,300,000,000 abroad, it is clear that the country is actually poorer, whatever the appearances may be.

If, then, the country is actually

[ocr errors]

poorer in its command of goods and services, how are we to explain the fact that most of the working classes and a large number of contractors and profiteers a majority of the population all together-have never had such a good time?' The answer seems to be that the war has caused a great change in the distribution of wealth, or of buying power. The minority have spent less on themselves and their own enjoyment than they did, and this abstinence- voluntary or compulsory — has meant a transfer of buying power, through the hands of the government, to the working classes and to those who have earned, or got, war profits. The class of small rentiers, living on fixed money incomes derived from investments, has been terribly hit both by high prices and by high taxation. This is the class which has really suffered war privation, except in so far as members of their families have been able to earn something by war work. The very rich have had a large part of their normal expenditure cut off by the enlistment of their men servants, grooms, gardeners, gamekeepers, chauffeurs, etc., by petrol restrictions, by the commandeering of their motor cars, houses, yachts, horses, etc., and by the impossibility of foreign travel. High taxation has relieved them of a considerable part of the savings that this enforced abstinence has produced, and the rest of it has gone into War Loans to be spent by the government and so handed over to the classes who were doing war work, or to the soldiers and sailors and their dependents. If one man who used to spend £40,000 a year on the amusements and diversions customary to his position has been able to spend only £10,000 of it during the war, the distribution of the odd £30,000 through, perhaps, 200 families by war expenditure would make a very considerable difference to the gen

eral standard of comfort. Whether retrenchment by the rich has been on this scale it is impossible to say, but at least it is clear that much of their expenditure has been forcibly cut down, and a good deal, no doubt, has been voluntarily cut down under the stimulus of patriotism, since people who have been accustomed to handling big incomes have usually more sense of responsibility in the spending of them than those who have lately and quickly acquired them. And it is satisfactory, from the point of view of the well-being of the country as a whole, to note that this widening of the distribution of buying power, and improvement of the workers' standard, to some extent will be permanent. Some people argue that the rich, as a whole, have grown richer by the war, owing to their big subscriptions to War Loans. But if, as seems likely, the large proportion of the debt charge will be raised at their expense, by heavy direct taxation, their share of after-war taxation will be bigger than their share of the interest on the debt.

Land and Water

THE CAUSE OF STRIKES

THERE are few signs in the world at present of the coming of that 'brotherhood of the classes' which some prophets foretold as the result of the war for democracy. From almost every country comes news of labor unrest on a large scale, and from most countries, of serious strikes often developing into civil disturbances. It is, of course, easy to exaggerate the significance of such movements, whose precise importance the continued activity of the various censorships makes it very difficult to ascertain. But enough reliable information comes through to make it certain that revolution is at least a

possibility in certain of the most important Allied countries.

As we write, it is by no means certain how the French and Italian strike movements will develop. It is clear that the immediate causes of the various stoppages both in Paris and in the provinces are almost purely economic; but it is equally clear that the undercurrent of political unrest is exceedingly strong, and that the movement of events may easily transform the strikes from economic into political phenomena. At present, the Confédération Générale du Travail is holding its hand; but if it joins in and declares a political general strike, it is impossible to say where the trouble will end. In Italy, the political character of the strikes, especially among the seamen, appears more plainly on the surface, and the refusal of certain crews to sail with munitions intended for Russia is obviously an event of first-class significance. But, even in Italy, it would be difficult to say whether political or economic causes play the greater part in the unrest. In Canada and the United States the origin of most of the trouble was certainly economic, and the character of the Winnipeg movement only shows how far in these days a purely economic strike is likely to carry the participants.

The plain fact is that all over Europe, and to an increasing extent in America also, the armies are mobilizing for something like a class war. Economic movements have a rapidly growing tendency to become political, not only because the workers possess a greatly increased power and are far more conscious of it, but also because their economic claims are animated by a steadily deepening hostility to the whole capitalist order of society. Not only do the workers feel stronger they have also a growing feeling that capitalism is insecure. The greatest

--

barrier to labor unrest before the war was the widespread conviction that capitalism was inevitable that it had been in possession ever since the workers could remember, and that there were no signs that it was likely to come to an end. To-day the world, and the workers, perhaps, most of all, have lost the feeling of certainty about anything. We have come through such changes already that no change for better or worse now seems altogether impossible. Empires, apparently strong and impregnable, have perished almost in a night; new nations have arisen; two great countries are actually governed by extreme Socialists, and several others by Socialists of a milder type. After the fall of the Hapsburgs, the Hohenzollerns, and the Romanoffs, after the coming of Soviet Russia and of Soviet Hungary, who, whatever his attitude toward these things, will dare to affirm that revolutionary social changes are impossible in his own country? Who will hold an untarnished faith in the permanence and inviolability of the old order?

In this country, we have so far been less affected than any Continental people by the prevailing unrest. But here, too, the same forces are at work. More than six months after the termination of hostilities, how different is our economic situation from that which was foreshadowed by the optimists who told us of the blessings of 'reconstruction.' We, too, are a prey to insecurity; we, too, are grown more tolerant of daring adventures and more credulous of Utopian speculations. Our manufacturers and traders, however grandiose the plans which they lay for the future, lack confidence. They know not what the morrow may bring forth, either at home or abroad. Accordingly, they tend to put off till to-morrow what they would do to-day if they felt secure, with the result that

« VorigeDoorgaan »